Alexandra Zeitz, St. Antony’s College, Oxford
Speakers:
Adam Bennett, St. Antony’s College, Oxford and
Robin McConnachie, Oxford Analytica
Chair: Stewart Fleming, St. Antony’s College, Oxford
When the IMF is called in during a time of
economic crisis, the programme agreed is often politically contentious. One of
the defining questions in the aftermath of the IMF’s intervention is
frequently: “did it work?” In late November, PEFM heard from Adam Bennett,
formerly of the IMF, about the effectiveness of IMF programmes in a region
where the Fund has played a prominent role in recent decades: the Balkans.
Robin McConnachie, who has acted as an advisor to governments in the region,
contributed his insights into what makes for successful reform programmes.
How does one capture the impact of an IMF
programme? Bennett explained that the Fund itself has grappled with the
numerous measurement challenges of evaluating effectiveness. Simple measures
comparing indicators before and after an IMF programme neglect the
counterfactual of how the country would be faring in the absence of an IMF
programme. Comparisons between countries with and without IMF programmes cannot
account for the fact that countries with IMF programmes often faced worse
conditions than those that received no programme.
The Fund has responded to these measurement
concerns by building complex models that attempt to capture the impact of
policy interventions. These models, however, can only be as accurate as the
assumptions they are built on. For his evaluation of the IMF’s programmes in
the Balkans, therefore, Bennett used simple comparisons between those Balkan
countries with and without IMF programmes and contrasted countries’ actual performance
with the targets set in the programme.
In this snapshot evaluation of IMF
interventions in the Balkans, Bennett showed that programmes appear, at first
glance, to have had a negligible impact. After the financial crisis, growth
fell from pre-crisis rates of 5% to 0% across the region, regardless of whether
countries had a programme with the IMF or not. Inflation rates across the
region averaged approximately 4-5% over the pre- and post-crisis period, with
no discernible difference between those countries with and without programmes.
Similarly, countries across the region seem to have had broadly similar current
account positions in the aftermath of the crisis, regardless of whether the IMF
intervened.
Yet, Bennett presented evidence that
suggests IMF programmes were in fact able to avert even worse crises in those
countries in which they operated. When accounting for the impact of foreign
direct investment flows, it appears that the balance of payments position of
those economies that ultimately received IMF intervention were weaker than
those that received no programme. Absent exceptional financing, and without any
private capital inflows (which had dried up) these balance of payments deficits
would have been forced immediately to zero, either through a severe contraction
of domestic demand or by a large devaluation (for countries with independent
currencies), or both, and thereby generate a much worse interim growth outlook
and/or inflation scenario than in fact occurred.
Bennett thus argued that the IMF provided
classic balance of payments financing to Balkan economies during the crisis. As
set out in the IMF’s Article I, the Fund’s purpose is (inter alia) to make it’s
resources “temporarily available” and “under adequate safeguards” (i.e., subject
to conditionality) so as to provide its members “with opportunity to correct
maladjustments in their balance of payments without resorting to measures
destructive of national or international prosperity”.
In reviewing the trajectory of IMF
programmes over recent decades, Bennett highlighted the declining role of
stringent conditions, even as the resources provided by IMF programmes in the
Balkans grew in the aftermath of the crisis. Tough quarterly and structural
performance criteria tapered off in IMF programmes after the mid-2000s, when
the IMF responded to the critiques that it had overreached and become
excessively intrusive in response to the Asian financial crisis. And yet, from
2011 onwards, there was a noticeable uptick in ‘prior action’ conditions
attached to IMF loans: actions the country must take in order to secure
disbursement of funds.
Robin McConnachie presented a more critical
view of the conditions attached to IMF programmes. Drawing on his experience
advising governments on the receiving end of such conditions, McConnachie
stressed the importance of local enthusiasm and support in order for reforms to
succeed. Securing such support requires diplomatic sensitivity about the
internal politics of relevant bureaucracies. Efforts to, for instance,
establish a local securities market will be dependent on the backing of a local
champion, ideally a cabinet minister. A particularly sensitive relationship is
the one between the Central Bank and the Ministry of Finance, both of whom are
needed for successful reforms, but who may have built up legacies of mistrust
and strained communication.
Though the IMF has corrected these mistakes
in later years, McConnachie argued that in the 1990s heyday of post-Soviet
liberalization and reform the IMF had often taken a ‘one-size-fits-all’
approach across the Balkan region. As programmes sprang up across the region, young
IMF staffers often took the lead, transposing policies that had been successful
in one context to a different country. It is not surprising, McConnachie
implied, if these programmes struggle to rouse the local enthusiasm required.
Both speakers stressed the importance of good
communication. The IMF and local governments must be careful to clearly explain
the intended benefits of reforms to the public in order to secure much-needed
legitimacy and political support. But this received some push-back from the
audience. Communicating the technical or long-term benefits of reforms may
ignore the severe costs (even if short-term) that they entail. Reforms,
particularly structural ones, will have distributional consequences and unleash
political backlash. While the Fund may wish to leave these questions to
domestic governments, it cannot wholly insulate itself from the politics of its
programmes.
No comments:
Post a Comment