Alexandra Zeitz (Global Economic Governance Programme, University of Oxford)
Presentation: Nicholas Morris, Balliol
College
Blogpost: Alexandra Zeitz, St.
Antony’s College
What is the relationship between trust and
law? And is it possible that some systems of law are better able to encourage
trust than others? In a PEFM seminar in October, Nicholas Morris presented a
research project investigating the role of Chinese legal traditions in
cultivating trust, examining whether tenets of Chinese law can be adopted
globally in order to rebuild trust in the economy, particularly in the
financial sector.
Morris’ comparative work on Chinese legal
traditions and trustworthy behavior is part of a larger research project, led
by Morris together with David Vines, on rebuilding trust in the financial
sector in the aftermath of the global financial crisis. Vines and Morris have
presented their work at PEFM in the past (see discussions of their
presentations in these two previous
posts)
and the circle of experts and academics linked to PEFM continue to engage with
this promising interdisciplinary research endeavor.
In order to function equitably and
effectively, financial markets require strong trust among participants. This
was Morris’ starting point. Merely relying on individuals’ desire for
approbation and maintaining their reputation is insufficient to ensure robust
trust. Instead, he argued, moral and normative structures are necessary to set
out accepted and approved patterns of behavior.
These codes of behavior have often been
part of religious doctrine, such as prohibitions on usury. Morris argued that
secular legal structures can perform a similar function, by laying out
society’s definition of acceptable behavior, establishing who is to be held responsible,
and meting out punishment. As an aside, Morris was skeptical, perhaps
excessively so, of whether contemporary religious norms and doctrines regarding
finance, especially in the case of Islamic finance, can truly encourage moral
behavior. Though many Islamic finance products do in fact do little to
challenge mainstream finance, doctrines of Islamic finance continue to be used
to argue for more sustainable finance based on principles of equitable risk
sharing. See, for instance, Adam Ng’s recent
book with Abbas Mirakhor and Mansor Ibrahim.
Comparing common law, civil law and
religious law to the Chinese legal framework, Morris ultimately argues that
China’s ancient legal traditions may be best suited to sustaining relationships
of trust. Chinese legal thought is composed of two strains: Confucianism and
legalism. Confucian thought holds that traditional customs and mores, well
understood throughout society, ought to be the means of inducing good, moral
behavior. As people internalize the agreed-upon norms, they not only become
better individuals, but also contribute to a more harmonious social order. This
vision of law, called li, regards
regulations and codified law as occasionally necessary, but less desirable
since it can lead to observance of rules without an internalization of the
ethics that underpin the rules.
A different strain of Chinese legal
thought, legalism, takes a more cynical view of human behavior and prioritizes
codified law and government regulation as a means of encouraging appropriate
behavior. This type of law is referred to as fa. As a school of thought, legalism emerged in the same historical
period as Confucianism, but has been reinforced by the importation of Western
legal principles throughout the 20th century.
The notion of li translates into a legal doctrine highly dependent on
relationships. For instance, Chinese legal practice makes extensive use of
arbitration rather than litigation. As such, Morris argues that li can be a helpful model in building
structures that encourage trustworthiness. He aims to further investigate the
claim that “resort to formal penalties and prohibitions…is advisable only where
it is not possible to use li or
relationship-based norms to encourage trustworthiness”.
At this early stage of the research
project, I would like to offer several pieces of constructive criticism,
several of which were also identified by the seminar audience.
Firstly, greater conceptual clarity of both
trustworthiness and trust is needed. Trustworthiness implies something about
the actor to be trusted as well as suggesting an assessment of whether or not
they merit trust, i.e. whether they are worthy
of trust. However, people often trust others who a third party might
conclude are decidedly not trustworthy. Trustworthiness may be a sufficient
condition for trust, but it is certainly not
a necessary condition. Is the project investigating legal determinants of
trust or of trustworthiness? Systems that encourage trust might not be the same
as those that limit deceitful, incompetent or unreliable behavior.
Secondly, though this comparative project
promises to be illuminating, there are several notes of caution. An audience
member familiar with the Chinese financial regulator stressed that the body has
made concerted efforts to formalize legal codes over the last decades in view
of the fact that relationship-based legal structures were thought to be vulnerable
to corruption. The current weaknesses in
the Chinese financial system, in part arising out of the informal ties between
banks and government officials, highlight potential risks.
It is important not to conflate Confucian
thought with contemporary Chinese legal practices, nor to conclude that simply
because Confucian legal teachings were aimed at cultivating trust they have in
fact historically been successful in doing so. Furthermore, in advocating that
these principles be adopted in legal systems outside of China, it is worth
investigating whether they are so culturally embedded that they would be
inappropriate, or at least difficult to integrate, in legal systems with
different historical traditions.
Finally, in order to head off the possible
critique that this project is looking for grounds on which to avoid tighter
regulation, it would be helpful to spell out more clearly the relationship
between trust sustained by relationships/li
and regulation/fa. Why is the trust
established by li preferable to that
created by fa? Is it not the nature
of the modern state that we trust our fellow citizens on the basis of adherence
to law? In massive, diffuse, and opaque financial markets can participants
establish the bonds and shared norms necessary for li? And can fa and li be mutually reinforcing?
No comments:
Post a Comment