Speaker: Ron Bird, University of
Technology, Sydney
Chair: David Vines, Balliol College, Oxford
How can we explain the existence of a
multi-trillion dollar industry that consistently underperforms? This is the
provocative question that Prof. Bird addressed in his seminar talk for PEFM. In
particular, he focused on asset managers, that is, those that invest other
people’s funds. In this arrangement, risk stays with the fund owners who get
the investment returns net of all costs, while managers charge an asset-based
fee and may charge a performance fee.
The size of the industry is impressive –
over 71 trillion USD worth of assets under management, with profits of 102
billion USD. The biggest division within is between active and passive
management. Active managers seek to pick stocks that outperform relative to a
benchmark index by overweighting better performing stocks. This is opposed to
passive management, which is becoming more and more popular in recent years,
accounting for up to one-third of US mutual funds.
Active management is supposed to deliver
two main benefits. First, active managers are expected to outperform their
benchmarks, thus making money for their clients. However, Prof. Bird cites
numerous studies demonstrating that as a group, active managers do not
outperform indices, and indeed underperform once fees are taken into account.
Even more, there is little evidence of consistency, so even outperforming
managers do not tend to remain like this for long. Second, active funds could improve
the price discovery mechanism, leading to improved allocative efficiency.
However, even as information and processing capabilities have increased
dramatically, research shows no evidence of pricing in equity markets becoming
more informationally efficient.
This leads Prof. Bird to his central
conundrum: why academic managers, who seem to not be delivering for their
clients or society, receive ever-increasing compensation? There seems to be a
priori several reasons. First, quality is almost impossible to measure in this
industry as performance is often driven by noise - due to the volatility of
equities, it takes about 40 years before one can confidently judge whether an
active manager is ‘good’ or not. Second, money is sticky – new money goes to
people who performed well recently, but if you don’t do an outrageous job,
people generally stay with you. Thus, it is an industry in which principals are
relatively less interested in the performance of the agents.
Based on these observations, Prof. Bird
presented several of his own empirical studies. The first one is related to how
funds change their strategy as they grow. Fund managers aim to maximize the
present value of their future fee income and, in doing so, choose how much
money to allocate to their own active bets and how much to just following the
index. Small funds have an incentive to be aggressive and follow their bets;
however, Prof. Bird finds that performance begins to decline with size.
His explanation is that when a manager has
more money under management, the cost of losing clients increases and outweighs
potential gains of following their judgment. At this point, managers allocate
more money to following indices, essentially turning their fund into an index one.
Even good managers are tempted to follow this route as using one’s ability
increases the probability of bad outcomes, thus creating incentives to lock in their
business rather than grow it.
Prof. Bird’s second paper looks at what he
dubs “the curse of the benchmarks”. In particular, he argues managers have
incentives to follow benchmarks close enough as to attribute any deviations to
‘tracking errors’ rather than underperformance, thus limiting business risk. In
this case, they end up buying stocks that are going up and sell stocks that are
going down in order to remain within this ‘tracking error’, essentially
reducing their bets and enforcing momentum trading.
This results in the ‘momentum life cycle’
of shares to which asset managers contribute. Stocks can thus come down due to
bad information signals relative to expectations, leading to a downward
momentum, even after they become cheap enough for ‘fundamental’ investors.
Eventually such fundamental traders offset momentum people, bringing in asset
managers again, who this time drive up value of stocks beyond its fair value,
setting it up for another swing in momentum. In this type of trading, tracking
constraints end up distorting the relationship between stock selection and the
construction of a portfolio as managers seek to minimize risks of making ‘bad
bets’ for their businesses.
Overall, Prof. Bird raises an intriguing
question, building up on similar observations by other researchers regarding
the disjunction between the popularity of active asset management and its
actual performance. As he acknowledges, explaining this contradiction is not
necessarily easy as the number of moving parts in the system is very high.
However, by focusing in particular on the incentives of asset managers
themselves in growing their business, he makes an interesting contribution to
existing scholarship.
Ivaylo Iaydjiev (St Antony’s College)
I have read many article here and learn many things from that, this was really helpful for me. Thank you so much for sharing this info with us and share your ideas with us.
ReplyDeleteAsset Management Software
Asset Tracking Software
Asset Management Software India
Asset Management Software Chennai